Chapter 18 wasn’t too difficult, but it introduced a lot of
new concepts and added onto old chapters. The chapter largely focused on labor,
both the demand and supply, but also briefly talked about land and capital, and
how a shift in one factor of production will affect the others. The markets
were seen as competitive, so it focused on a lot of the earlier stuff, which
made it easier to understand, but it is very dense. Most of the ways to read
the labor market was through its marginal values, such as knowing that
profit-maximizing firms hire each factor up to the point at which the value of
the marginal product of the factor equals its price, and factor demand reflects
the value of the marginal product of that product. In equilibrium, each factor
is compensated according to its marginal contribution to the production of
goods and services.
Monday, December 7, 2015
Sunday, November 29, 2015
Chapter 17
Chapter 17 covered oligopolies and how they worked. It was a
pretty simple chapter, especially because it built off of the previous
chapters, especially chapter 16. An oligopoly is a market with a few firms,
where their actions and interactions affect each other, they are between a
competitive and monopoly market, and the more firms there are, the more it acts
like a competitive market, with price closer to marginal cost and quantity sold
closer to the social benefit; self-interest prevents it from reaching a monopolistic
profit. In a perfect world, the oligopoly will reach a monopolistic profit,
where the firms maximize their profit, though it would not reach a socially beneficial
quantity sold. Instead, the firms will reach, Nash equilibrium, where the
economic actors interacting with one another each choose their best strategy
given the strategies the others have chosen, due to the tension between
cooperation and self-interest. There is also the prisoners’ dilemma, in which
cooperation would benefit both parties, but self-interest and dominant strategy
usually makes them choose a strategy in which both ultimately are worse off. In
some instances, the “prisoners” don’t turn each other in and both receive the
most efficient price, but this usually happens in players who do play more than
once, learning that cooperation works best. In real life, due to regulation (the
Sherman Act), even if firms were interested in cooperation and working it out
so all parties could reach the maximized profit, it is difficult because they aren’t
even allowed to discuss prices and quantity agreements.
Tuesday, November 17, 2015
Chapter 16
Chapter 16 discussed monopolistic competition, and given
that it builds off of our previous knowledge, it wasn’t an awful chapter.
Monopolistic competitive markets have aspects for both a monopoly and perfectly
competitive market, where there are multiple firms, with different categories. This
can fall under books and movies, which there are many publishers and works, but
each is different from each other. A monopolistic competitive market still
allows free entry into a market, as well as exit, and wants to maximize profit.
At profit maximization, marginal revenue is equal to marginal cost. It is
similar to a monopoly in that is a price maker, the price must be above
marginal cost, doesn’t necessarily produce welfare-maximizing output. It is
similar to a perfectly competitive market in that it has many firms, has free
entry in the long run, but cannot earn economic profits in the long run. The graphs
seems fairly easily to understand, especially after the last chapter, nothing
too new or surprising. I think at this point it is just remembering and
understanding which traits the market shares with competitive and monopoly. The
rest of the chapter discussed advertisements and brand names, their benefits
and critiques, and how that affects the market.
Monday, November 9, 2015
Chapter 15
This chapter focused on monopolies
and how they operate. It compared them to a competitive firm or market,
commenting on their differences and similarities, but also on how decide on
production, prices, and how they are regulated. The chapter kept referring to
how a certain rule or application was the same as in competitive markets, which
helped since I have a stronger understanding of it. The idea of deadweight
losses and the graph is still an iffy idea to me, but I think the class lecture
should help. Monopolies arise from three factors: a firm owns a key resource
for production, the government gives a single from the rights to produce a
good, or the costs of one firm to produce a good is less than if other firms
joined the market. Since monopolies have so much market power, they decide on
the quantity to produce and the price to charge, but that doesn’t mean they can
charge whatever they want. Their demand is downwards sloping, so the more the
charge, the less of a demand, unlike price takers who jus decided the quantity
to produce in a horizontal demand curve. Monopolies are regulated through
pricing, antitrust laws, make them government owned, or are left alone, since
the market can reach a socially profitable equilibrium on its own at times.
It’s a fairly easy chapter, but the
graphs can get a bit confusing, I should be able to clear that up, and be
reassured by going over the material is class.
Sunday, November 1, 2015
Chapter 14
Chapter 14 covered the firms in competitive markets and
their costs and firms. A big theme was what causes a firm to shut down or exit
a market. Meaning that it compared the costs firms face in perfect competitive
markets to their profits, both in the short and long run. The chapter
introduces many new equations and additions to old familiar graphs. Like, most
chapters, this stuff seems pretty common sense-y, but also like one mix up
could make you mess up a whole concept. Overall, a decently easy chapter, for
now. Some ideas the chapter covers is a switch from marginal cost to marginal
revenue and how that helps analyze how well a firm is doing. For instance, if
marginal revenue is less than marginal cost, the firm is losing profit and
should decrease their production. And marginal revenue and cost are equal when
the firm is producing at maximum profit. We learn that firms choose to shut
down, which is temporary and they still lose fixed cost, when their market
price is less than the average variable cost, and a market will exit a market
the price is less than the average total cost, and enter when price is more
than average total cost. In some instances, a firm will be more profitable when
it shuts down instead of exiting a market, because it of the sunk costs (fixed
costs that still need to be paid during unproductivity), which can be irrelevant
(this idea is still iffy to me).
Wednesday, October 28, 2015
Chapter 13
Chapter 13 seems to make sense once you read it, but I am
worried about the new vocabulary added as well as the graphs introduced. The
graphs more than the vocabulary. The chapter focuses on the costs in an economy
and market. When a person starts a business, their costs aren’t just the money
they put into it, we have to account for their opportunity costs (implicit
costs, and usually an economic value). An economists will anyways, not so much
an account. They only look at explicit costs vs the total revenue, the whole
money made minus the money they spent would give them clear profits.
The graphs worry me because it isn’t straight lines anymore;
the graphs curve depends on the circumstances, so drawing them is going to be
more difficult, and even the graphs with overlapping curves causes a slight
panic. The short run and long run graph is the most confusing one, but with
given time I think it’ll start to click.
The costs are also divided into categories: implicit, explicit,
fixed, variable, marginal. The groups may overlap, but still their distinctions
are pretty apparent and even by looking at the word choice, it doesn’t seem too
bad to memorize/learn.
Article Review #4
I’ll start off by saying Carmen Reinhart was much easier to
understand compared to Stockman. It was also a much shorter article, I think
mostly because Stockman got a little too involved in his views. Reinhart talks
about the financial crisis and its connection to the Chinese market and
economy. And basically how everything connects to China’s economy. She also
kept a pretty neutral ground throughout the article, while still getting to the
same conclusion as Stockman: we are in big trouble.
One useful and notable thing she mentions: financial crises
tend to share the following, “significant slowdown in economic growth and
exports, unwinding of asset-price booms, growing current-account and fiscal
deficits, rising leverage, and a reduction or outright reversal in capital inflows.”
Not all of it makes sense, but it’s not too difficult to put together, and she
goes on to explain how debt is playing a large in all of this. The big
question: where is it coming from? She doesn’t provide an answer, but clarifies
that the massive growth of depth isn’t being sourced right; underlying factors
are taking place and right now, we have some we need to uncover. The rest of
the article gave examples of her points, but kept it minimal, straight to the
point and moving on, which, after Stockman, was quite refreshing.
Tuesday, October 20, 2015
Chapter 11
A relatively easy chapter, chapter 11 makes sense to me, but
the book goes into how the distinctions between public goods and common
resources (and some of the other types of good) can become fuzzy and so I worry
that labeling the types of characteristics can become slightly “subjective” in
a sense, or at least easy to miss a detail and miss label it. This chapter
begins to split goods into four categories according to two characteristics: is
the good excludable, and is it rival in consumption. The categories discussed
were public goods (neither excludable nor rival in consumption) and common
resources (not excludable but they are rival in consumption). The other two are
private goods (excludable and rival in consumption) and a good produced by a
natural monopoly (excludable but not rival in consumption). The free-rider
problem eludes to how certain goods cannot be in a private market because
free-riders (those who benefit from a good but avoid paying it) don’t pay for
the good and then the market doesn’t thrive or the supplier doesn’t have an initiative
to supply the good because they don’t receive a profit. This is when the
government steps in to either supply the good for the public through
taxes/subsidies, or initiatives. A cost-benefit analysis studies the costs and
benefits of providing a good to society, and this can be difficult in certain
situations, such as dealing with people’s lives. Overall, I feel pretty good
about the chapter, and just hope that the different concepts don’t become
muddled in my head.
Sunday, October 18, 2015
Chapter 10
Chapter 10 was very dense. While all the concepts introduced
make sense, there’s a lot to them. Chapter 10 focuses on externalities, which
are the external benefits and/or cost to society a market will have, in the big
picture, but is also the uncompensated impact on one person’s actions on the
well-being of a bystander. A negative externality means that the bystander pays
for the impact (e.g. pollution caused by big factories) and a positive externality
means the bystander benefits from the impact (e.g. education creates
well-educated neighbors and societal advances). In dealing with both positive
and negative externalities, the government can take an active role to reduce
the negative or enhance the positive externalities through subsidies or
regulation and corrective taxes. For regulations, I wonder whether price
ceilings and floors would either fall under it or correlate, or because they do
not deal with externalities directly they are considered completely separate? While
I understand that corrective taxes are better, in that case, would those taxes
still create a deadweight, or would the shrinkage of the market be considered
only beneficial to society and therefore not be considered? And with tradable permits,
does the idea only fall under pollution, or would other substances be
considered for allowing permits? Also trading permits is still a hazy idea to
be just because of my more liberal views, but in either case, could this
eventually lead to a decline in the amount of pollution or would it probably
just stay capped at its max allowed amount?
Thursday, October 15, 2015
Article review #3
David stockman's article was confusing to say the least. He uses acronyms and vocabulary and names people and assumed his readers with be completely on board with what he is saying. Which is a reasonable assumption, but I don't understand it. While I look up a decent amount of his references, it doesn't always clear things up. He is passionate though, and obviously believes the economy is in the tank, or getting there. I'm not sure if he's a pessimist or a realist. He believes that the Fed has allowed a decline in our economy and he really thinks Bernanke is playing a big role on covering it up. He talks about rising inflation rates and zero-interest policies and an economic bubble. While I can see how it's bad, not all of it fits in together yet. He even connects the economic disparity to Brazil and their financial bubble. The real players he seems to keep referring to central banks, and mentions the increase in debt world wide. While I understand stockman's style and rhetoric more than before, the article still proved to leave me stumped except for the knowledge that the economy needs major help from non corrupt banks or government officials.
Monday, October 12, 2015
Chapter 8
Chapter 8 wasn’t too bad to
understand, but I did have to take my time to look and analyze the graphs along
with the sections they correlated with to make sure the concepts made sense.
Once the ideas processed, it was easy to see how they could be thought of as
common sense or obvious responses. Hopefully I’ll still think that on test day.
The chapter focused on taxation
effects on consumer and producer surplus, and how it negatively affects their
gains. The tax reduces the amount of surplus gained by both consumers and
producers, and the loss of the surplus often exceeds the gain of tax revenue
gained by the government creating a deadweight loss. The deadweight loss
reflects the loss of trades or market reduction caused the loss of incentives
from producers and/or consumers created from the tax. The measure of the
deadweight loss can be analyzed through the elasticity of the market; the more
elastic a market, the larger the deadweight loss, and the larger the tax, the
larger the deadweight loss. The tax revenue will increase at first with the
increase of the tax, but will then decline with the growth of the tax until the
market shuts down from loss of incentives. The chapter seems logical to follow,
I think practice with the graphs would be helpful though.
Tuesday, October 6, 2015
Chapter 7
Chapter 7 covered markets and welfare; it discussed how to
see a market via the surpluses from consumers and sellers. The chapter overall
was easy to understand but I think just practicing the graphs and getting a
hang for everything would be useful. The money that consumers are willing to
pay for their goods minus the money they actually pay for their good is called
a consumer surplus, initially measuring the amount they save, or their “bargain.”
The money sellers make minus the amount they were willing to give their good
for is the producer surplus, showing the amount they gain. A large surplus,
from both consumers and producers, demonstrates a good measure of economic
well-being. In a free market, the buys who are willing to spend the most will
always be included in the market, and the sellers willing to sell the goods for
the cheapest will also always be included in the market. A perfect free market
will have a lot of surplus from both sides, will have reached a natural
equilibrium, and most at attempts are equalizing the market will disrupt this
system. A market should be left alone to find its own equilibrium in most cases
and will usually find its most efficient manner. The concepts in the chapter
were very tangible and understandable.
Sunday, October 4, 2015
Article #2
In this article, Stockman talks about how the U.S. economy
is going to be facing big trouble. Due the language in the article, I didn’t fully
understand why or how this was taking place, but I understood that this is not
just an American problem, the whole world’s economy is going to plummet soon.
He talks about China’s problems and mentions how Brazil is facing massive consumer
decline. Stockman makes a point to talk about Wall Street and the idea of the
cover up of the economy but an elaboration in class would help me fully understand
the point he was making. From my understanding, there was more things were
being bought for more than they were worth, or perhaps I mixed it up and it is
the other way around. Either way, there is a deflation problem that needs to be
addressed, instead of pushed aside. While the graphs made the content a bit
more clear, the article is still a jumble of economic confusion for me. He
makes a connection to 2008/2007 which I can only assume is the recession that
took place, and yet the connection is a bit hazy; understandably, we will face
a recession of the same, perhaps larger, extremes, but I’m at a loss at to
whether it will be for the same reasons, either because they were not resolved
or the attempt at fixing things only made matters worse. Nevertheless, Stockman
does not seem happy and seems to believe this could have been preventable, but
is no longer at this point.
Friday, October 2, 2015
Chapter 6
Chapter 6 focuses on how government policies affect the
prices and puts a “ceiling” and “floor” on them. For the most part, this
chapter was understandable but going over it class would just help to make sure
I fully understand the content. A price ceiling in the legal maximum price a
good can cost and a price floor is the legal minimum a good can cost. The
government creates these with polices and laws, such as rent control and minimum
wage, and is meant to help the service be rationed between sellers and buyers,
but can result in excess supply or demand. The government also uses taxes to
affect the market, causing equilibrium of the quantity to fall and shrink the
size of the market. The tax causes a wedge on the price paid and the price
received by the buyer and the seller, so the movement of the equilibrium causes
the buyers to pay more, but the sellers receive less. In these cases, the
buyers and sellers then share a “tax burden” caused by the wedge. On the other
hand, the burden usually falls on the less elastic side of the market because
it can be less responsive to the tax by changing the quantity bought or sold
since those goods tend to be more needed, and not seen as a luxury. The
concepts chapter 6 covers seem pretty straight forward but the details can be a
bit offsetting. I’m sure with review I’ll better understand the ideas
expressed.
Friday, September 25, 2015
Ch 5
Chapter five began to introduce
more mathematical methods, but still kept a huge focus on conceptual and graphical
understanding.
We were
introduced to elasticity, which is the measure of the change of quantity demanded
or quantity supplied to one of its determinants, and applied to demand is
referred to price elasticity of demand; applied to supply is referred to price elasticity
. So the price of elasticity of demand measures how much the quantity demanded responds
to changes in the price, and price of elasticity of supply measures how much
the quantity supplied responds to changes in the price. If the elasticity is
less than one, the quantity demanded/supplied moves proportionately less than
the price (inelastic), when it is one, the quantity demanded/supplied moves
perfectly with the price, just about at equilibrium, and when it is greater
than one, the quantity demanded/supplied moves proportionately more than the
price (elasticity). Using a time horizon , supplied/demand tend to be more elastic
in long runs than in short ones, where people can gradually pick something up
or stop buying it, and where sellers can change their productions, close shops,
or even more sellers come into the scene.
Total
revenue is the total amount paid for a good, measured by the price of good multiplied
by the total amount of the good sold. For the inelastic, it falls as price
rises, and for the elastic demand curve, it falls as the price rises.
Monday, September 21, 2015
Article Review #1
The article on its own was very confusing, and while I made notes and looked up many of the words or people mentioned to try to get a better understanding, it was still difficult to make all the connections. The author was discussing how Keynesian economics doesn't really work and really only benefits those on Wall Street, rather than actually taking into account the households and how they borrow money. From my understanding, this concept is actually causing inflation, and a bubble in the economy, and tries to show positive interest rates actually "help" the economy. While the U.S. prints more money, that money doesn't seem to be going into households, but back into the stocks, where business growth is actually slowed.
I did not fully understand Stockman's idea of tightening and his graphs, but it is evident that he does not believe that the Fed has tightened enough, in contrast to what Keynesian economics tried to show. I did not understand his connection to household debt, saying it how gone flat and even decreased. Does the Fed's balance sheet show an increase in money, in which case, is that not good, even if it doesn't directly affect the household borrowing and spending? Or is that the problem, in which the Federal balance sheet changes but household spending and borrowing doesn't? Wouldn't we want household debt to decrease? So do low interest rates benefit households and high interest rates benefit Wall Street? Overall, the idea of an inflation bubble does seem as something to worry about.
Thursday, September 17, 2015
Ch 4
Chapter four goes into markets and the correlations of
supply and demand. A market, some more organized than others, run usually on
competition, supply, and demand. Demand often false into the realm of price, so
the higher the price of a good, the lower the demand, and vise versa (law of
demand). Demand can then be split into two categories: individual and market.
Individual demand being exactly what it sounds like, the demand and willingness
of an individual to pay for a good, and the market demand simple adds up the
individual demands. A shift in demand can take place due to income, prices,
taste, expectations, and the number of buyers in question. Demand can also be
altered due to government and policy interventions, which can increase of
decrease demands of goods, even if it is not the good in question. Supply works
in a similar fashion, as prices rise, the supply rises as well, but when it
drops, you can expect a decline in supply. The individual supply makes up the
market supply, though the market supply shows the total quantity supplied at
any price. Similar to the demand, supply can change because of input prices, technological
advances, expectations, and the number of sellers in the market. Supply and
demand is then needed at an equilibrium where the demand meets the supply
exactly, and the seller and buyer can both be satisfied. It is up to the market
to reach the equilibrium through a “trial and error” method in which prices
rise and fall for goods to try to find that equilibrium so that there is no
surplus or shortage of goods.
Sunday, September 13, 2015
Chapter 3
Chapter three addresses principles one, two, and five: people face trade-offs, the cost of something is what you give up to get it, and trade can make everyone better off. Even if two people are able to produce the same products, it may still be beneficial for both to trade their products. Person A would specialize in Product 2, and Person B would specialize in Product 1; this especially works when Person A is more efficient in producing Product 2 and Person B is more efficient in producing Product 1.This is not always the case and Person A may be more efficient in producing both Product 1 and Product 2, but trade would still benefit both due to their opportunity cost and comparative advantage. In this case, both people would find themselves leaning towards producing more of one product and trading their excess production for the other person’s excess production, finding they both have more of each than if they were self sufficient.
This same concept is then applied to two people specializing in one area, or even countries trading and benefiting from it.
This same concept is then applied to two people specializing in one area, or even countries trading and benefiting from it.
Subscribe to:
Posts (Atom)